Divisional
Performance and Transfer Pricing
1. Divisionalisation: Divisionalisation is a term for
the division of an organisation into divisions. Each divisional manager is
responsible for the performance of the division. A division may be a cost
centre (responsible for its costs only), a profit centre (responsible for
revenues and profits) or an investment centre or Strategic Business Unit
(responsible for costs, revenues and assets).
In general, a large organisation can be structured in one of two ways: functionally (all activities of a
similar type within a company, such as production, sales and research, are
under the control of the appropriate departmental head) or divisionally (split into divisions in accordance with the products
or services made or provided).
Divisional managers are therefore responsible for all
operations (production, sales, and so on) relating to their product, the
functional structure being applied to each division. It is possible, of course,
that only part of a company is divisionalised and activities such as
administration are structured centrally on a functional basis with the
responsibility of providing services to all
divisions.
1.1 Decentralisation: In general, a divisional structure will lead to
decentralisation of the decision making process and divisional managers may
have the freedom to set selling prices, choose suppliers, make product mix and
output decisions, and so on. Decentralisation is, however, a matter of degree,
depending on how much freedom divisional managers are given.
1.2 Advantages of divisionalisation
(a) Divisionalisation can improve the quality of
decisions made because divisional managers (those taking the decisions)
know local conditions and are able to make more informed judgements. Moreover,
with the personal incentive to improve the division's performance, they ought
to take decisions in the division's best interests.
(b) Decisions should be taken more quickly because
information does not have to pass along the chain of command to and from top
management. Decisions can be made on the spot by those who are familiar with
the product lines and production processes and who are able to react to changes
in local conditions quickly and efficiently.
(c) The authority to act to improve performance should motivate divisional managers.
(d) Divisional organisation frees top management from detailed involvement in day-to-day
operations and allows them to devote more time to strategic planning.
(e) Divisions provide valuable
training grounds for future members of top management by giving them
experience of managerial skills in a less complex environment than that faced
by top management.
(f) In a large business organisation, the central head office will not have the management
resources or skills to direct operations closely enough itself. Some
authority must be delegated to local operational managers.
1.3 Disadvantages of divisionalisation
(a) A danger with divisional accounting is that the business
organisation will divide into a number of self-interested segments, each acting
at times against the wishes and interests of other segments. Decisions might be
taken by a divisional manager in the best interests of their own part of the
business, but against the best interest of other divisions and possibly against
the interests of the organisation as a whole.
A task of head office
is therefore to try to prevent
dysfunctional decision-making by individual divisional managers. To do
this, head office must reserve some power and authority for itself so that
divisional managers cannot be allowed to make entirely independent decisions. A
balance ought to be kept between decentralisation of authority
to provide incentives and motivation, and
retaining centralised authority to ensure that the organisation's divisions
are all working towards the same target, the benefit of the organisation as a
whole (in other words, retaining goal
congruence among the organisation's separate divisions).
(b) It is claimed that the costs of activities that are common to all divisions, such as
running the accounting department, may
be greater for a divisionalised structure than for a centralised structure.
(c) Top management,
by delegating decision-making to divisional managers, may lose control since they are not aware of what is going on in the
organisation as a whole. (With a good system of performance evaluation and
appropriate control information, however, top management should be able to
control operations just as effectively.)
1.4 Responsibility accounting: Responsibility accounting is the term used to describe
decentralisation of authority, with the performance of the decentralised units
measured in terms of accounting results.
With a system of responsibility accounting there are five
types of responsibility centre: cost
centre; revenue centre; profit centre; contribution centre; and investment
centre.
The creation of divisions allows for the operation of a
system of responsibility accounting.
There are a number of types of responsibility accounting unit, or
responsibility centre that can be used within a system of responsibility
accounting.
In the weakest form of decentralisation a system of cost centres might be used. As
decentralisation becomes stronger the responsibility accounting framework will
be based around profit centres. In
its strongest form investment centres are
used.
Type of responsibility centre
|
Manager has control over …
|
Principal performance measures
|
Cost centre
|
Controllable costs
|
Variance analysis Efficiency measures
|
Revenue centre
|
Revenues only
|
Revenues
|
Profit centre
|
Controllable costs
Sales prices
(including transfer prices)
|
Profit
|
Contribution centre
|
As for profit centre
except that expenditure is reported on a marginal cost basis
|
Contribution
|
Investment centre
|
Controllable costs
Sales prices (including transfer prices) Output volumes
Investment
in non-current assets
and working capital
|
Return on investment Residual income Other financial ratios
|
2. Return on investment (ROI): The performance of an
investment centre is usually monitored using either or both return on investment (ROI) and residual income (RI).
ROI is generally regarded as the key performance measure.
The main reason for its widespread use is that it ties in directly
with the accounting process, and is identifiable from the income statement
and balance sheet. However, it does have limitations, as we will see later in
this chapter.
Return on investment (ROI) shows how much profit has
been made in relation to the amount of capital invested and is calculated as
(profit/capital employed) × 100%.
For example, suppose that a company has two investment
centres, A and B, which show results for the year as follows.
A
|
B
|
|
$
|
$
|
|
Profit
|
60,000
|
30,000
|
Capital employed
|
400,000
|
120,000
|
ROI
|
15%
|
25%
|
Investment centre A has made double the profits of
investment centre B and in terms of profits alone has therefore been more
'successful'. However, B has achieved its profits with a much lower capital
investment and so has earned a much higher ROI. This suggests that B has been a
more successful investment than A.
2.1 Measuring ROI: There is no generally agreed
method of calculating ROI, and it can have behavioural implications and
lead to dysfunctional decision-making when used as a guide to investment
decisions. It focuses attention on short-run performance whereas investment
decisions should be evaluated over their full life.
ROI can be measured in different ways.
2.1.1 Profit after depreciation as a % of net assets
employed
This is probably the most
common method, but it does present a problem. If an investment centre
maintains the same annual profit, and keeps the same assets without a policy of
regular replacement of non-current assets, its ROI will increase year by year
as the assets get older. This can give a
false impression of improving performance over time.
For example, the results of investment centre X, with a
policy of straight-line depreciation of assets over a five-year period, might
be as follows.
Non - current
|
|||||||
Year
|
assets
|
Depreciation
|
NBV
|
Working
|
Capital
|
||
at cost
|
in the
year
|
(mid year)
|
capital
|
employed
|
Profit
|
ROI
|
|
$'000
|
$'000
|
$'000
|
$'000
|
$'000
|
$'000
|
||
0
|
100
|
10
|
110
|
||||
1
|
100
|
20
|
90
|
10
|
100
|
10
|
10.0%
|
2
|
100
|
20
|
70
|
10
|
80
|
10
|
12.5%
|
3
|
100
|
20
|
50
|
10
|
60
|
10
|
16.7%
|
4
|
100
|
20
|
30
|
10
|
40
|
10
|
25.0%
|
5
|
100
|
20
|
10
|
10
|
20
|
10
|
50.0%
|
This table of figures is intended to show that an investment
centre can improve its ROI year by
year simply by allowing its non-current
assets to depreciate, and there could be a disincentive to investment centre managers to reinvest in new or replacement assets, because the centre's ROI
would probably fall.
This example has used a mid-year NBV but a year end or start
of year NBV can also be used.
A further disadvantage of measuring ROI as profit divided by
net assets is that, for similar reasons, it is not easy to compare fairly the performance
of investment centres. For example, suppose that we have two investment
centres.
Investment
centre P Investment
centre Q
Working capital
|
$
|
$
20,000
|
$
|
$
20,000
|
Non-current assets at cost
|
230,000
|
230,000
|
||
Accumulated depreciation Net book value
|
170,000
|
60,000
|
10,000
|
220,000
|
Capital employed
|
80,000
|
240,000
|
||
Profit
|
$24,000
|
$24,000
|
||
ROI
|
30%
|
10%
|
Investment centres P and Q have the same amount of working
capital, the same value of non-current assets at cost and the same profit.
However, P's non-current assets have been depreciated by a much bigger amount
(presumably P's non-current assets are much older than Q's) and so P's ROI is
three times the size of Q's ROI. The conclusion might therefore be that P has
performed much better than Q. This comparison, however, would not be 'fair',
because the difference in performance might be entirely attributable to the age
of their non-current assets.
The arguments for
using net book values for calculating ROI
(a) It is the 'normally
accepted' method of calculating ROI.
(b) Organisations are continually buying new non-current
assets to replace old ones that wear out and so, on the whole, the total net book value of all non-current
assets together will remain fairly
constant (assuming nil inflation and nil growth).
2.1.2 Profit after depreciation as a % of gross assets
employed: Instead of measuring ROI as return on net assets, we could
measure it as return on gross assets i.e. before depreciation. This would remove the problem of ROI increasing over
time as non-current assets get older.
If a company acquired a non-current asset costing $40,000,
which it intends to depreciate by $10,000 pa for four years, and if the asset
earns a profit of $8,000 pa after depreciation, ROI might be calculated on net
book values or gross values, as follows.
NBV (mid-
|
ROI based on
|
ROI based on
|
|||
Year
|
Profit
|
year value)
|
NBV
|
Gross value
|
gross value
|
$
|
$
|
$
|
|||
1
|
8,000
|
35,000
|
22.9%
|
40,000
|
20%
|
2
|
8,000
|
25,000
|
32.0%
|
40,000
|
20%
|
3
|
8,000
|
15,000
|
53.3%
|
40,000
|
20%
|
4
|
8,000
|
5,000
|
160.0%
|
40,000
|
20%
|
The ROI based on net
book value shows an increasing trend
over time, simply because the asset's value is falling as it is
depreciated. The ROI based on gross book value suggests that the asset has performed consistently in each of the
four years, which is probably a more valid conclusion.
However, using gross book values to measure ROI has its disadvantages. Most important of these
is that measuring ROI as return on gross assets ignores the age factor, and does not distinguish between old and new
assets.
(a) Older non-current
assets usually cost more to repair
and maintain, to keep them running. An investment centre with old assets
may therefore have its profitability reduced by repair costs, and its ROI might
fall over time as its assets get older and repair costs get bigger.
(b) Inflation and
technological change alter the cost of
non-current assets. If one investment centre has non-current assets bought
ten years ago with a gross cost of $1 million, and another investment centre in
the same area of business operations has non-current assets bought very
recently for $1 million, the quantity and technological character of the
non-current assets of the two investment centres are likely to be very
different.
2.1.3 Constituent elements of the investment base: Although
we have looked at how the investment base should be valued, we need to consider
its appropriate constituent elements.
(a) If a manager's
performance is being evaluated, only those assets which can be traced
directly to the division and are controllable
by the manager should be included. Head office assets or investment centre
assets controlled by head office should not be included. So, for example, only
those cash balances actually maintained within an investment centre itself
should be included.
(b) If it is the performance of the investment centre that
is being appraised, a proportion of the
investment in head office assets would need to be included because an
investment centre could not operate without the support of head office assets
and administrative backup.
2.1.4 Profits: We have looked at how to define the
asset base used in the calculations but what about profit? If the performance of the investment centre
manager is being assessed it should seem reasonable to base profit on the revenues and costs controllable by the manager and
exclude service and head office costs except those costs specifically
attributable to the investment centre. If it is the performance of the investment centre that is being assessed, however,
the inclusion of general service and head office costs would seem reasonable.
The profit figure for ROI should always be the amount
before any interest is charged.
2.1.5 Massaging the ROI: If a manager's large bonus
depends on ROI being met, the manager may feel pressure to massage the measure.
The asset base of the ratio can be altered by increasing/decreasing
payables and receivables (by speeding up or delaying payments and receipts).
2.2 ROI and new investments: If investment centre
performance is judged by ROI, we should expect that the managers of investment
centres will probably decide to undertake new capital investments only if these new investments are likely to
increase the ROI of their centre.
Suppose that an investment centre, A, currently makes a
return of 40% on capital employed. The manager of centre A would probably only
want to undertake new investments that promise to yield a return of 40% or
more, otherwise the investment centre's overall ROI would fall.
For example, if investment centre A currently has assets of
$1,000,000 and expects to earn a profit of $400,000, how would the centre's
manager view a new capital investment which would cost $250,000 and yield a
profit of $75,000 pa?
Without the new investment
|
With the new investment
|
|
Profit
|
$400,000
|
$475,000
|
Capital employed
|
$1,000,000
|
$1,250,000
|
ROI
|
40%
|
38%
|
The new investment would
reduce the investment centre's ROI from
40% to 38%, and so the investment centre manager would probably decide not to undertake the new investment.
If the group of companies of which investment centre A is a
part has a target ROI of, say, 25%, the new investment would presumably be seen
as beneficial for the group as a whole.
But even though it promises to yield a return of 75,000/250,000 = 30%, which is
above the group's target ROI, it would still make investment centre A's results
look worse. The manager of investment centre A would, in these circumstances,
be motivated to do not what is best for the organisation as a whole, but what
is best for his division.
ROI should not be used to guide investment decisions but
there is a difficult motivational problem.
If management performance is measured in terms of ROI, any decisions which
benefit the company in the long term but which reduce the ROI in the immediate
short term would reflect badly on the manager's reported performance. In other
words, good investment decisions would make a manager's performance seem worse than if the wrong investment
decision were taken instead.
3. Residual income (RI): RI can sometimes give
results that avoid the behavioural problem
of dysfunctionality. Its weakness is
that it does not facilitate comparisons between investment centres nor does it
relate the size of a centre's income to the size of the investment.
An alternative way of measuring the performance of an
investment centre, instead of using ROI, is residual income (RI). Residual
income is a measure of the centre's profits after deducting a notional
or imputed interest cost.
(a) The centre's profit is after deducting depreciation
on capital equipment.
(b) The imputed cost of capital might be the organisation's
cost of borrowing or its weighted average cost of capital.
Residual income is
a measure of the centre's profits after deducting a notional or imputed
interest cost.
3.1 The
advantages and weaknesses of RI compared with ROI: The advantages of using RI
(a) Residual income
will increase when investments earning above the cost of capital are
undertaken and investments earning below the cost of capital are eliminated.
(b) Residual income
is more flexible since a different cost of capital can be applied to
investments with different risk characteristics.
The weakness
of RI is that it does not facilitate comparisons between investment
centres nor does it relate the size of a centre's income to the size of the
investment.
3.2 RI versus
ROI: marginally profitable investments: Residual income will increase if a new investment is undertaken which
earns a profit in excess of the imputed interest charge on the value of the
asset acquired. Residual income will go up even if the investment only just
exceeds the imputed interest charge, and this means that 'marginally
profitable' investments are likely to be undertaken by the investment centre
manager.
In contrast, when a
manager is judged by ROI, a marginally profitable investment would be less
likely to be undertaken because it would reduce the average ROI earned by the
centre as a whole.
3.2.1 Example:
ROI versus residual income: Suppose
that Department H has the following profit, assets employed and an imputed
interest charge of 12% on operating assets.
$
|
$
|
|
Operating profit
|
30,000
|
|
Operating assets
|
100,000
|
|
Imputed interest (12%)
|
12,000
|
|
Return on investment
|
30%
|
|
Residual income
|
18,000
|
Suppose now that an
additional investment of $10,000 is proposed, which will increase operating
income in Department H by $1,400. The effect of the investment would be:
$
|
$
|
|
Total operating income
|
31,400
|
|
Total operating assets
|
110,000
|
|
Imputed interest (12%)
|
13,200
|
|
Return on investment
|
28.5%
|
|
Residual income
|
18,200
|
If the Department H
manager is made responsible for the department's performance, they would resist
the new investment if they were to be judged on ROI, but would welcome
the investment if they were judged according to RI, since there would be a
marginal increase of $200 in residual income from the investment, but a fall of
1.5% in ROI.
The marginal
investment offers a return of 14% ($1,400 on an investment of $10,000) which is
above the 'cut-off rate' of 12%. Since the original return on investment was
30%, the marginal investment will reduce the overall divisional performance.
Indeed, any marginal investment offering an accounting rate of return of less
than 30% in the year would reduce the overall performance.
4. Transfer
pricing: Transfer prices
are a way of promoting divisional
autonomy, ideally without prejudicing the measurement of divisional performance or discouraging overall corporate profit maximisation.
Transfer prices
should be set at a level which ensures that profits for the organisation as a
whole are maximised.
Transfer pricing is used when divisions of an organisation
need to charge other divisions of the same organisation for goods and services
they provide to them. For example, subsidiary A might make a component that is
used as part of a product made by subsidiary B of the same company, but that
can also be sold to the external market, including makers of rival products to
subsidiary B's product. There will therefore be two sources of revenue for A.
(a) External sales
revenue from sales made to other organisations
(b) Internal sales
revenue from sales made to other responsibility centres within the same
organisation, valued at the transfer price
A transfer price is the price at which
goods or services are transferred from one department to another, or from one
member of a group to another.
4.1
Problems
with transfer pricing
4.1.1
Maintaining the right level of divisional autonomy: Transfer prices are particularly appropriate
for profit centres because if one
profit centre does work for another the size of the transfer price will affect
the costs of one profit centre and the revenues of another.
However, as we have
seen, a danger with profit centre accounting is that the business organisation
will divide into a number of
self-interested segments, each acting at times against the wishes and
interests of other segments. Decisions might be taken by a profit centre
manager in the best interests of their own part of the business, but against
the best interests of other profit centres and possibly the organisation as a
whole.
4.1.2 Ensuring
divisional performance is measured fairly: Profit centre managers tend to put their own profit performance above
everything else. Since profit centre performance is measured according to the
profit they earn, no profit centre will want to do work for another and incur
costs without being paid for it. Consequently, profit centre managers are
likely to dispute the size of transfer prices with each other, or disagree
about whether one profit centre should do work for another or not. Transfer
prices affect behaviour and decisions by
profit centre managers.
4.1.3 Ensuring
corporate profits are maximised: When there are disagreements about how much work should be transferred
between divisions, and how many sales the division should make to the external
market, there is presumably a profit-maximising
level of output and sales for the organisation as a whole. However, unless
each profit centre also maximises its own profit at this same level of output,
there will be interdivisional disagreements about output levels and the
profit-maximising output will not be achieved.
4.1.4 The ideal
solution: Ideally a transfer
price should be set at a level that overcomes these problems.
(a) The transfer
price should provide an 'artificial' selling price that enables the transferring division to earn a return for
its efforts, and the receiving
division to incur a cost for benefits received.
(b) The transfer
price should be set at a level that enables profit centre performance to be measured 'commercially'. This means that the transfer price should
be a fair commercial price.
(c) The transfer
price, if possible, should encourage profit centre managers to agree on the
amount of goods and services to be transferred, which will also be at a level
that is consistent with the aims of the organisation as a whole, such as maximising company profits.
In practice it is
difficult to achieve all three aims.
4.2 General
rules: The limits within which transfer prices should
fall are as follows.
• The minimum: The sum of the supplying division's marginal
cost and opportunity cost of the item transferred.
• The maximum: The lowest market price at which the
receiving division could purchase the goods or services externally, less any
internal cost savings in packaging and delivery.
The minimum results from the fact that the supplying division will not agree to
transfer if the transfer price is less than the marginal cost + opportunity
cost of the item transferred (because if it were, the division would incur
a loss).
The maximum results from the fact that the receiving division will buy the item at the
cheapest price possible.
4.2.1 Example: general
rules: Division X produces
product L at a marginal cost per unit of $100. If a unit is transferred
internally to division Y, $25 contribution is forgone on an external sale. The
item can be purchased externally for $150.
• The minimum. Division X will not agree to a transfer
price of less than $(100 + 25) = $125 per unit.
• The maximum. Division Y will not agree to a transfer
price in excess of $150.
The difference
between the two results ($25) represents the savings from producing internally
as opposed to buying externally.
4.2.2
Opportunity cost: The opportunity cost included in
determining the lower limit will be one of the following.
(a) The maximum
contribution forgone by the supplying division in transferring internally rather than selling goods externally.
(b) The contribution forgone by not using the same facilities in the
producing division for their next best
alternative use.
If there is no external market for the item being
transferred, and no alternative uses for
the division's facilities, the transfer
price = standard variable cost of
production.
If there is an external market for the item being
transferred and no alternative, more profitable use for the facilities
in that division, the transfer price =
the market price.
4.2.3 Example:
The transfer price at full and spare capacity: The factors that influence the transfer
price charged when divisions are operating at full capacity and spare
capacity are best illustrated using an example.
Until recently,
Strike Ltd focused exclusively on making soles for work boots and football
boots. It sold these rubber soles to boot manufacturers. Last year the company
decided to take advantage of its strong reputation by expanding into the
business of making football boots. As a consequence of this expansion, the
company is now structured as two independent divisions, the Boot Division and
the Sole Division.
The Sole Division
continues to make rubber soles for both football boots and work boots and sells
these soles to other boot manufacturers. The Boot division manufactures leather
uppers for football boots and attaches these uppers to rubber soles. During its
first year the Boot Division purchased its rubber soles from outside suppliers
so as not to disrupt the operations of the Sole Division.
Strike management
now wants the Sole Division to provide at least some of the soles used by the
Boot Division. The table below shows the contribution margin for each division
when the Boot Division purchases from an outside supplier.
Boot
Division
$
|
Sole
Division
$
|
||
Selling price of football
boot
|
100
|
Selling price of sole
|
28
|
Variable cost of making boot
(not including sole)
|
45
|
Variable cost per sole
|
21
|
Cost of sole purchased from
outside suppliers
|
25
|
||
Contribution margin per unit
|
30
|
Contribution margin per unit
|
7
|
The information
above indicates that the total contribution margin per unit is $37 ($30 + $7).
Required: What would be a fair transfer price if the
Sole Division sold 10,000 soles to the Boot Division?
Solution: The answer depends on how busy the Sole Division
is – that is, whether it has spare capacity. No spare capacity
As indicated above,
the Sole Division charges $28 and derives a contribution margin of $7 per sole.
The Sole Division has no spare capacity and produces and sells 80,000
units (soles) to outside customers. Therefore, the Sole Division must receive
from the Boot Division a payment that will at least cover its variable cost per
sole plus its lost contribution margin per sole (the opportunity cost).
If the Sole Division cannot cover that amount (the minimum transfer price), it should not sell soles to the Boot
Division. The minimum transfer price that would be acceptable to the Sole
Division is $28, as shown below.
$21 (variable cost)
+ $7 (opportunity cost) = $28
Spare capacity: The minimum transfer price is different if
a division has spare capacity. Assume the Sole Division produces 80,000 soles
but can only sell 70,000 to the open market. As a result, it has available
capacity of 10,000 units. In this situation, the Sole Division does not lose
its contribution margin of $7 per unit, and therefore the minimum price it
would now accept is $21 as shown below.
$21 (variable cost)
+ $0 (opportunity cost) = $21
In this case the
Boot Division and the Sole Division should negotiate
a transfer price within the range of
$21 and $25 (cost
from outside supplier).
4.3 The use of
market price as a basis for transfer prices: If an external market price
exists for transferred goods, profit centre managers will be aware of the
price they could obtain or the price they would have to pay for their goods on
the external market, and they would inevitably compare this price with the
transfer price.
4.3.1 Example:
Transferring goods at market value: A company has two profit centres, A and B. A sells half its output on
the open market and transfers the other half to B. Costs and external revenues
in an accounting period are as follows.
A
|
B
|
Total
|
|
$
|
$
|
$
|
|
External sales
|
8,000
|
24,000
|
32,000
|
Costs
of production
|
12,000
|
10,000
|
22,000
|
Company profit
|
10,000
|
Required: What are the consequences of setting a
transfer price at market value?
Solution: If the transfer price is at market price, A
would be happy to sell the output to B for $8,000, which is what A would get by
selling it externally instead of transferring it.
A
|
B
|
Total
|
|||
$
|
$
|
$
|
$
|
$
|
|
Market sales
|
8,000
|
24,000
|
32,000
|
||
Transfer sales
|
8,000
|
-
|
|||
16,000
|
24,000
|
||||
Transfer costs
|
-
|
8,000
|
|||
Own costs
|
12,000
|
10,000
|
22,000
|
||
12,000
|
18,000
|
||||
Profit
|
4,000
|
6,000
|
10,000
|
The transfer sales of A are self-cancelling
with the transfer cost of B, so that the total profits are unaffected by
the transfer items. The transfer price simply spreads the total profit between
A and B.
Consequences
(a) A earns the
same profit on transfers as on external sales. B must pay a commercial price
for transferred goods, and both divisions will have their profit measured in a
fair way.
(b) A will be
indifferent about selling externally or transferring goods to B because the
profit is the same on both types of transaction. B can therefore ask for and
obtain as many units as it wants from A.
A market-based transfer price therefore
seems to be the ideal transfer
price.
4.4
The
merits of market value transfer prices
4.4.1 Divisional
autonomy: In a
decentralised company, divisional managers should have the autonomy to make output, selling and buying decisions which appear to be in the best interests of the division's
performance. (If every division optimises its performance, the company as a
whole must inevitably achieve optimal results.) Thus a transferor division should be given the freedom to sell output on the
open market, rather than to transfer it within the company.
'Arm's length'
transfer prices, which give profit centre managers the freedom to negotiate
prices with other profit centres as though they were independent companies,
will tend to result in a market-based transfer price.
4.4.2 Corporate
profit maximisation: In
most cases where the transfer price is at market price, internal transfers should be expected,
because the buying division is
likely to benefit from a better
quality of service, greater flexibility and dependability of supply. Both divisions may benefit from cheaper costs of administration, selling and
transport. Using a market price as the transfer price would therefore result in decisions which would be in the
best interests of the company or group as a whole.
4.4.3 Divisional
performance measurement: Where
a market price exists, but the transfer price is a different amount (say,
at standard cost plus), divisional managers will argue about the volume of internal transfers.
For example, if
division X is expected to sell output to division Y at a transfer price of $8
per unit when the open market price is $10, its manager will decide to sell all
output on the open market. The manager of division Y would resent the loss of
their cheap supply from X, and would be reluctant to buy on the open market. A
wasteful situation would arise where X sells on the open market at $10, where Y
buys at $10, so that administration, selling and distribution costs would have
been saved if X had sold directly to Y at $10, the market price.
4.5 The
disadvantages of market value transfer prices: Market value as a transfer price does have
certain disadvantages.
(a) The market price may be a temporary one,
induced by adverse economic conditions or dumping, or it might depend on the
volume of output supplied to the external market by the profit centre.
(b) A transfer price at market value might,
under some circumstances, act as a
disincentive to use up any spare capacity in the divisions. A price based
on incremental cost, in contrast, might provide an incentive to use up the
spare resources in order to provide a marginal contribution to profit.
(c) Many products do not have an equivalent market price so that the price of a
similar, but not identical, product might have to be chosen. In such
circumstances, the option to sell or buy on the open market does not really
exist.
(d) There might be
an imperfect external market for the
transferred item so that, if the transferring division tried to sell more
externally, it would have to reduce its selling price.
4.6 Cost-based
approaches to transfer pricing: Problems arise with the use of cost-based
transfer prices because one party or the other is liable to perceive them
as unfair.
Cost-based
approaches to transfer pricing are often used in practice, because in practice
the following conditions are common.
(a) There is no external market for the product that
is being transferred.
(b) Alternatively,
although there is an external market, it is an imperfect one because the market price is affected by such factors
as the amount that the company setting the transfer price supplies to it, or
because there is only a limited external demand.
In either case
there will not be a suitable market price on which to base the transfer price.
4.6.1 Transfer
prices based on full cost: Under
this approach, the full cost (including
fixed overheads absorbed) incurred by the supplying division in making the
'intermediate' product is charged to the receiving division. The obvious
drawback to this is that the division supplying the product makes no profit on its work so is not
motivated to supply internally. In addition, there are a number of alternative
ways in which fixed costs can be accounted for. If a full cost-plus approach is used, a profit margin is also included in this transfer price. The
supplying division will therefore gain some profit at the expense of the buying
division.
4.6.2 Example:
Transfer prices based on full cost: Suppose a company has two profit centres, A and B. A can only sell half
its maximum output of 800 units externally because of limited demand. It
transfers the other half of its output to B which also faces limited demand.
Costs and revenues in an accounting period are as follows.
A
$
|
B
$
|
Total
$
|
|
External sales
|
8,000
|
24,000
|
32,000
|
Costs
of production in the division
|
13,000
|
10,000
|
23,000
|
Profit
|
9,000
|
Division A's costs
included fixed production overheads of $4,800 and fixed selling and
administration costs of $1,000.
There are no
opening or closing inventories. It does not matter, for this illustration,
whether marginal costing or absorption costing is used. For the moment, we
shall ignore the question of whether the current output levels are profit
maximising and congruent with the goals of the company as a whole.
If the transfer
price is at full cost, A in our example would have 'sales' to B of $6,000
(($13,000 – 1,000) × 50%). Selling and administration costs are not included, as these are
not incurred on the internal transfers. This would be a cost to B, as follows.
A
|
B
|
Total
|
|||
$
|
$
|
$
|
$
|
$
|
|
Open market sales
|
8,000
|
24,000
|
32,000
|
||
Transfer sales
|
6,000
|
-
|
|||
Total sales, inc transfers
|
14,000
|
24,000
|
|||
Transfer costs
|
-
|
6,000
|
|||
Own costs
|
13,000
|
10,000
|
23,000
|
||
Total costs, inc transfers
|
13,000
|
16,000
|
|||
Profit
|
1,000
|
6,000
|
9,000
|
The transfer sales of A are self-cancelling
with the transfer costs of B so that total profits are unaffected by the transfer items. The transfer price simply spreads
the total profit of $9,000 between A and B.
The obvious drawback to the transfer price at cost
is that A makes no profit on its
work, and the manager of division A would much prefer to sell output on the
open market to earn a profit, rather than transfer to B, regardless of whether
or not transfers to B would be in the best interests of the company as a whole.
Division A needs a profit on its transfers in order to be motivated to supply
B; therefore transfer pricing at cost is inconsistent with the use of a profit
centre accounting system.
An intermediate product is one that is
used as a component of another product; for example, car headlights or food
additives.
4.6.3 Transfer
price at variable cost: A
variable cost approach entails charging the variable cost (which we assume to
be the same as the marginal cost) that has been incurred by the supplying
division to the receiving division.
The problem is that
with a transfer price at marginal cost the supplying
division does not cover its fixed costs.
4.7 Identifying
the optimal transfer price: Here
are some guiding rules for identifying the optimal transfer price.
(a) The ideal transfer price should reflect the opportunity cost of sale to
the supply division and the opportunity cost to the buying division.
Unfortunately, full information about opportunity costs may not be easily
obtainable in practice.
(b) Where a perfect external market price exists and
unit variable costs and unit selling prices are constant, the opportunity cost of transfer will be external market price or external market price less savings in
selling costs.
(c) In the absence of a perfect external market price
for the transferred item, but where unit variable costs are constant, and the sales price per unit of the end product is
constant, the ideal transfer price should
reflect the opportunity cost of the resources consumed by the supply division
to make and supply the item and so should be at standard variable cost + opportunity cost of making the transfer.
(d) When unit variable costs and/or unit selling
prices are not constant, there will be a profit- maximising level of output and the ideal transfer price will only be found by sensible negotiation and careful analysis.
(i) Establish the
output and sales quantities that will optimise the profits of the company or
group as a whole.
(ii) Establish the
transfer price at which both profit centres would maximise their profits at
this company-optimising output level.
There may be a
range of prices within which both profit centres can agree on the output level
that would maximise their individual profits and the profits of the company as
a whole. Any price within the range would then be 'ideal'.
4.8
Transfer
pricing calculations
4.8.1 Sub-optimal
decisions: Note that, as
the level of transfer price increases, its effect on a division within the
organisation could lead to sub-optimalisation problems for the organisation as
a whole.
4.8.2 Example:
Sub-optimal decisions: For
example, suppose division B could buy the product from an outside supplier for
$10 instead of paying $15 ($6,000/ (800/2)) to division A. This transfer
price would therefore force division B to buy the product externally at $10 per
unit, although it could be manufactured internally for a variable cost of
$(13,000 – 4,800 – 1,000)/800 = $9 per unit.
Although division B
(the buying division) would save ($15 – $10) = $5 per unit by buying
externally, the organisation as a whole would lose $400, as follows.
Per Unit
|
units
|
$
|
|
Marginal cost
of production
|
9
|
External purchase cost
|
10
|
Loss
if buy in
|
1
|
The overall loss on
transfer/purchase of 400 units is therefore 400 × $1 = $400.
This loss of $1 per
unit assumes that any other use for the released capacity would produce a
benefit of less than $400. If the 400 units could also be sold externally for
$20 per unit, the optimal decision for the organisation as a whole would be to
buy in the units for division B at $10 per unit.
Per unit
$
Market price
|
20
|
Marginal cost
|
9
|
Contribution
|
11
|
Loss if buy-in
|
(1)
|
Incremental profit
|
10
|
The overall incremental profit would
therefore be 400
´ $10 = $4,000.
|
4.8.3 Example:
Prices based on full cost plus: If the transfers are at cost plus a margin of, say, 10%, A's sales to B
would be $6,600 ($13,000 – 1,000) × 50% × 1.10).
A
|
B
|
Total
|
|||
$
|
$
|
$
|
$
|
$
|
|
Open market sales
|
8,000
|
24,000
|
32,000
|
||
Transfer sales
|
6,600
|
-
|
|||
14,600
|
24,000
|
||||
Transfer costs
|
-
|
6,600
|
|||
Own costs
|
13,000
|
10,000
|
23,000
|
||
13,000
|
16,600
|
||||
Profit
|
1,600
|
7,400
|
9,000
|
Compared to a
transfer price at cost, A gains some
profit at the expense of B. However, A makes a bigger profit on external
sales in this case because the profit mark-up of 10% is less than the profit
mark-up on open market sales. The choice of 10% as a profit mark-up was
arbitrary and unrelated to external market conditions.
The transfer price fails on all three criteria (divisional
autonomy, performance measurement and corporate profit measurement) for
judgement.
(a) Arguably, the
transfer price does not give A fair revenue or charge B a reasonable cost, and
so their profit performance is distorted.
It would certainly be unfair, for example, to compare A's profit with B's
profit.
(b) Given this
unfairness, it is likely that the autonomy
of each of the divisional managers is under
threat. If they cannot agree on what is a fair split of the external
profit, a decision will have to be imposed from above.
(c) It would seem
to give A an incentive to sell more goods externally and transfer less to B.
This may or may not be in the best
interests of the company as a whole.
In fact, we can
demonstrate that the method is flawed
from the point of view of corporate profit maximisation. Division A's total
production costs of $12,000 include an element of fixed costs. Half of
division A's total production costs are transferred to division B. However,
from the point of view of division B, the cost is entirely variable.
The cost per unit
to A is $15 ($12,000 800) and this includes a fixed element of $6 ($4,800 ÷ 800), while division
B's own costs are $25 ($10,000 400) per unit, including a fixed element of
$10 (say). The total variable cost is really $9 + $15 = $24, but
from division B's point of view the variable cost is $15 + $(25 –
10) = $30. This means that division B will be unwilling to sell the
final product for less than $30, whereas any price above $24 would make a
contribution to overall costs. Thus, if external prices for the final product
fall, B might be tempted to cease production.
4.8.4 Example:
Transfer prices based on variable or marginal cost: A variable or marginal cost approach entails
charging the variable cost (which we assume to be the same as the marginal
cost) that has been incurred by the supplying division to the receiving
division. As above, we shall suppose that A's cost per unit is $15, of which $6
is fixed and $9 variable.
A
|
B
|
Company as a whole
|
||||
$
|
$
|
$
|
$
|
$
|
$
|
|
Market sales
|
8,000
|
24,000
|
32,000
|
|||
Transfer sales
|
3,600
|
-
|
||||
11,600
|
24,000
|
|||||
Transfer costs
|
-
|
3,600
|
||||
Own variable costs
|
7,200
|
6,000
|
13,200
|
|||
Own fixed costs
|
5,800
|
4,000
|
9,800
|
|||
Total costs and transfers
|
13,000
|
13,600
|
23,000
|
|||
(Loss)/Profit
|
(1,400)
|
10,400
|
9,000
|
4.8.5 Divisional
autonomy, divisional performance measurement and corporate profit maximisation
(a) This result is deeply
unsatisfactory for the manager of division A who could make an additional
$4,400 ($(8,000 –
3,600)) profit if no goods were transferred to division B, but all were sold
externally.
(b) Given that the
manager of division A would prefer to transfer externally, head office
are likely to have to insist that internal transfers are made.
(c) For the company
overall, external transfers only would cause a large fall in profit, because
division B could make no sales at all.
Point to note: Suppose no more than the current $8,000
could be earned from external sales and the production capacity used for
production for internal transfer would remain idle if not used. Division A
would be indifferent to the transfers at marginal cost, as they do not
represent any benefit to the division.
If more than the
$8,000 of revenue could be earned externally (i.e. division A could sell more
externally than at present), division A would have a strong disincentive to
supply B at marginal cost.
No comments:
Post a Comment